Is Conscious Capitalism A Conceptual Mess?
Conscious Capitalism (CC) is featured prominently in the latest issue of the California Management Review (CMR) (Spring 2013, Vol. 55 No. 3.). In an article entitled “Conscious Capitalism Firms: Do They Behave as Their Proponents Say?”, Chong Wang, an Assistant Professor at the Naval Postgraduate School in Monterey, California challenges the “scientific status” of the theory of conscious capitalism. Using a sample of 17 CC firms he compared their results with a matched set of non-CC equivalents against several distinguishing criteria developed by the proponents of CC.
Professor Wang tested four assertions. These were that, compared with non-CC firms, CC firms have:
- Lower gross margins (gross profit as a percentage of sales)
- Higher profit margins (net income as a percentage of sales)
- Lower selling, general and administrative (SG&A) as a percentage of sales
- Lower marketing costs (advertising expenses as a percentage of sales)
In his findings he rejected #1 – CC firms have higher gross margins than their non-CC rivals, a finding that should not surprise anyone who has ever shopped at Whole Foods! He found support for #2 – CC firms have fatter bottom lines. He could find no evidence to support assertions #3 and #4. He developed an analysis that suggested that CC firms were no less attentive to the stock markets than non-CC firms; they managed their earnings just like their non-CC rivals. In short, Professor Wang questioned the entire conscious capitalism narrative, including how firms were selected as being members of the group.
Professor Raj Sisodia responded to this criticism in the same issue of CMR. He stated that CC proponents have now developed a deeper understanding of CC firms. The “single greatest driver of superior financial performance for highly conscious businesses is their ability to generate superior sales volume on a given asset base.” CC proponents now agree that many CC firms have very healthy gross margins but that they don’t “consciously seek to maximize” them. He went on to argue that operating efficiencies of CC firms are subtle and cannot be detected by the study of publicly available numbers whose expense categories are too gross. As for guidance given to stock markets and earnings management, Professor Sisodia seemed to concede Wang’s critique but argued that it was “largely peripheral to our arguments” and he contended that CC “is a robust philosophy that is deeply attuned to the exigencies of the times which we live in.”
While agreeing that publicly-available data permits limited analysis, I must confess that Professor Sisodia’s commentary came across to me as unpersuasive and designed to “save the appearances” of the CC theory/philosophy/paradigm. In a Response to the Commentary (in the same issue) Chong Wang was withering in his criticism. He applied philosopher Karl Popper’s criteria for a scientific theory – refutability, consistency, and general applicability – to CC and concluded that it met none of these tests, seriously diminishing “the scientific status of CC theory.” More importantly, he questioned why, if CC is such a superior business paradigm, it is not being more widely adopted and challenged Sisodia’s claim that the degree of attention given to managing earnings by CC firms was peripheral to the CC model.
A Conceptual Muddle
It’s pretty clear that CC is in a real conceptual mess. It’s not a “scientific theory”, at least according to management scientists like Chong Wang, and, as I have argued elsewhere, it is not a paradigm. Sisodia calls CC a “philosophy” but he seems to use the word in a casual way, without suggesting any ontology, epistemology or methodology. It sounds more like a perspective than a philosophy. In reality what we call “conscious capitalism” is a practice, a variation on the set of practices that we call “management”. We need to understand what “it” is in practical terms; how it begins and the circumstances under which it can flourish and be sustained. Effective managers don’t care whether a practice is based on “scientific” theories; they just want to know whether it works in a sustainable, cost-effective way.
So what is to be done? Anyone trying to change the way we practice management faces a wicked problem with multiple roots and complex causes. One of problems is that the attempt to apply science and the scientific method to management problems has gone far beyond its legitimate boundaries. Aristotle, the father of the approach, always contended that his analytical methods could be applied only to things that “cannot be other than what they are” i.e. things that don’t change – objects. Today we would extend that boundary to include things that change in predictable ways – machines. But in the late 1950s management science set out to make the behavior of people predictable so that the scientific method could be applied to them. In theory this meant the adoption of “as-if” assumptions like the economists e.g. that people are rational utility-maximizers. In practice it meant creating contexts in which people would behave in predictable ways e.g. in organizations by using the control systems and processes of top-down hierarchy, and in the population at large by using mass advertising and the full spectrum of influence techniques.
As everything grew in the post WWII period this approach seemed to work for a while – the hope grew among academics that perhaps management could indeed become a “science” – but as growth faded and the need for innovation became apparent, the flaws of an approach that regarded technology and creativity as “exogenous” to the system became clearer.
Humans are reflective creatures and fundamentally dislike being treated either as objects or as machines. As the unwritten contract between corporations and their employees broke down, their behavior became more and more dysfunctional. The result was Anglo-Saxon capitalism in its present pickle, with practices like conscious capitalism being hailed as a way out. Unfortunately that’s not going to work; the roots of the problem are far too tangled and deep. We need to go back to our basic assumptions about human nature and the human mind. We need a framework that can embrace and contain the technical rationality of management science in a matrix of values that reassert the existence of boundaries between what Max Weber called zweckrationale and wertrationale. As readers of this blog will know, I believe that an ecological perspective is a good place to start.
This entry was posted in Change, General, Leadership, Strategy and tagged Anglo-Saxon capitalism, Aristotle, Chong Wang, complex systems, conscious capitalism, ecological perspective, innovation, Karl Popper, Max Weber, narrative, Raj Sisodia, The New Ecology of Leadership, Whole Foods. Bookmark the permalink. ← Complexity and the Plexus Institute: The Critical Role of Intuition in Action and Thought T-shaped People: Deduction, Induction, Abduction and Systems Thinking →-
Archives
- May 2024
- February 2023
- December 2022
- September 2022
- May 2022
- March 2022
- February 2022
- November 2021
- October 2021
- January 2021
- November 2020
- September 2020
- July 2020
- June 2020
- May 2020
- April 2020
- February 2020
- January 2020
- September 2019
- July 2019
- April 2019
- March 2019
- November 2018
- October 2018
- March 2018
- July 2017
- April 2017
- November 2016
- October 2016
- June 2016
- May 2016
- April 2016
- March 2016
- December 2015
- November 2015
- October 2015
- May 2015
- March 2015
- January 2015
- December 2014
- November 2014
- September 2014
- July 2014
- June 2014
- May 2014
- April 2014
- March 2014
- February 2014
- January 2014
- December 2013
- November 2013
- October 2013
- September 2013
- August 2013
- July 2013
- June 2013
- May 2013
- April 2013
- March 2013
- February 2013
- January 2013
- December 2012
- November 2012
- October 2012
- September 2012
- August 2012
- July 2012
- June 2012
- May 2012
- April 2012
- March 2012
- February 2012
-
Meta
One Response to Is Conscious Capitalism A Conceptual Mess?